Mises Wire

Economic Growth Requires More Than Low Interest Rates

Many commentators and economic experts are of the view that the Federal Reserve is running out of tools to keep the economy going given the very low level of interest rates. It is also argued that despite a steep downtrend in the policy rate since 1980, the underlying growth of the US economy has been following a down trend.

This must be contrasted with the previous period when the underlying trend in the federal funds rate was heading up while the underlying growth of economic activity followed a rising trend.

Why Is Economic Growth Slowing? 

Many experts are of the view that the key reason behind subdued economic growth notwithstanding low interest rates is a decline in the population growth and the lack of sufficient technological innovations. It is held that slower population growth coupled with a lower speed of technological progress undermines economic expansion.

A slower pace of new inventions weakens investment in the infrastructure, which in turn also undermines economic growth, so it is held. In addition to slower population growth, experts also attribute the decline in the trend growth of economic activity to subdued productivity.

This decline in turn is explained by the slowdown in innovations and investment in the infrastructure.

The main question which has puzzled all economists is why has there been a downtrend in investment growth given the decline in interest rates? Most experts are silent on this. Some of them have argued that the downtrend in interest rates is on account of subdued economic growth, which prompted the central bank to lower interest rates.

Other experts have embraced the view that the downtrend in economic growth is on account of long-term factors that pushes the economy onto a declining path of economic growth.

The problem here is not of a cyclical nature but rather of a secular trend, which cannot be handled by monetary policy, so it is held. Hence it is advocated that the solution should come from a more aggressive fiscal policy, which could lift the underlying economic growth trend by boosting investment in the infrastructure, which in turn will give boost to more innovations etc.

Given the seemingly positive correlation between low interest rates and low economic growth some commentators have also questioned the validity of the Austrian Business Cycle Theory. 

After all why hasn’t the low interest rate policy of the Federal Reserve succeeded in reviving economic activity as the Austrian school implies? Furthermore, during 1960-1979 when interest rates were in an uptrend, investment trend growth was also heading up, i.e. contrary to what the Austrian theory would suggest, so it is held.

Economic Growth Requires more Than Just Low Interest Rates 

Even if we were to ignore the measurement problems of various macro economic data that popular economics is employing, the Austrian business cycle theory is not only about the mechanical manipulation of rates by the central bank that cause boom–bust economic cycles.

It is about the overall monetary policy of the central bank and its effect on money supply growth and interest rates. Furthermore, the theory pays attention to the damage that loose monetary policy does to the process of wealth formation and to the pool of real wealth.

A keyconcept in wealth formation is that production must precede consumption. It is necessary to produce useful goods that can be exchanged for other useful goods.

When a baker produces bread, he doesn’t produce everything for his own consumption. Most of the bread he produces is exchanged for the goods and services of other producers, implying that through the production of bread the baker exercises his demand for other goods.

To put it differently, his demand is fully covered (i.e., funded by the bread that he has produced).

Demand Depends on Production 

Demand therefore, cannot stand by itself and be independent; it is limited by prior production, which serves as a means of securing various goods and services.

What thwarts individuals' demand for goods and services, is the availability of means at their disposal to appropriate all the goods and services individuals want. These means however do not spring "out of thin air." They have to be produced.

The production of goods and services is constrained by the real pool of wealth: the final goods available to provide sustenance to the economic process. The pool of wealth is the quantity of final goods available in an economy to support future production. If it requires one year of work for a man to build a tool, but he has only enough apples saved to sustain him for one month, then the tool will not be built-and the man will not be able to increase his productivity.1

The Role of Money in the Market Economy

In a market economy, money has just one role — to provide the services of a medium of exchange. Money permits the product of one specialist to be exchanged for the product of another specialist.

The exchange of something for something also means that consumption doesn’t precede production. That is, we first have to produce a useful product before it can be exchanged for money and only then we could exchange money for goods we desire. Consumption is fully funded by preceding production.

The Effects of Easy Money 

On account of loose monetary policy and the subsequent increase in the money supply, the process of wealth transferring from wealth generators to the holders of the newly created money is set in motion. Since this new money was generated out of “thin air,” nothing was exchanged for it hence we have here an exchange of nothing for something.

This means the holders of newly printed money have taken from the pool of real wealth without giving anything back in return.Consequently, this puts pressure on the pool of real wealth. Similarly to government, these holders of newly created money are engaged in non-wealth generating activities. (These activities sprang up on the back of money pumping. In the free unhampered environment these activities, which ranked as low priority would not be undertaken.)

Again loose monetary policy undermines the process of wealth generation and weakens the pool of real wealth.

One could however, argue that any form of investment takes from the pool of wealth without giving anything in return in the short term. This is true; hence if the present flow of production of final consumer goods is not fast enough, then the pool of wealth is going to come under pressure in the short term.

In the case of productive investments, one should expect in the future a strengthening in the pool of wealth. This is, however, not the case with respect to non-productive investments.

Subsequently, with a weaker pool it gets much harder for the businesses to keep the pace of investment growing at a growing pace. As a result, the pace of productivity growth follows suit.

The Effects on Time Preference

Note that a downward pressure on the pool of real wealth is likely to result in an increase in individuals’ time preferences — a greater preference towards present consumption versus the future consumption, which puts an upward pressure on the underlying real interest rate.

To put it differently, an increase in the underlying real interest rate is in response to the increase in individuals’ time preferences.

This in turn implies a further downward pressure on the pace of investment, which is, of course, bad news for productivity growth.

Please note that, contrary to popular thinking, it is not an increase in interest rates as such that weakens investment, but the increase in individuals’ time preferences. In short, a fall in investment and an increase in interest rates are in response to the increase in individuals’ time preferences.

In order to ascertain qualitatively the damage inflicted onto the pool of wealth all that we have to do is to inspect the money supply data.

In Q1 1960 our measure of US money supply, AMS, stood at $147 billion. By Q2 2016 this measure stood at $4,400 billion — an increase of 2,283%. Note that since Q1 2000 to Q2 this year the AMS has increased by 188%.

With such massive monetary pumping it stands to reason that the wealth generation process has come under severe pressure.

Another possible way to illustrate the pressure on the pool of real wealth is to look at the so called real interest rates. On this during the period 1959 to 1979 Moody’s AAA real corporate bond yields stood on average at 1.98% against 4.26% during 1980 to July 2016. Abstracting for the data problems and the distortions inflicted by the Fed to the corporate bond market one could argue that this raises the likelihood of an increase in time preference since 1980. Subsequently, one could argue that this raises the likelihood that the pool of real wealth since 1980 has been under pressure, all other things being equal.

We can only suggest that notwithstanding loose monetary policy, the wealth generating private sector has managed to create wealth,however as time went by on account of massive money pumping, their ability to keep the pool of wealth growing at an expanding pace has likely been curtailed.

To conclude we can suggest that contrary to popular thinking loose monetary policy cannot grow an economy but it definitely can destroy it and in this sense it is very potent.

Frank Shostak's consulting firm, Applied Austrian School Economics, provides in-depth assessments and reports of financial markets and global economies. Contact: email.

  • 1Richard von Strigl, Capital and Production, Mises Institute, p.8.
image/svg+xml
Note: The views expressed on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises Institute.
Support Liberty

The Mises Institute exists solely on voluntary contributions from readers like you. Support our students and faculty in their work for Austrian economics, freedom, and peace.

Donate today
Group photo of Mises staff and fellows